THE COLLIERY GUARDIAN AM© JOURNAL OF THE COAL AND IRON TRADES. Vol. CXVL FRIDAY, DECEMBER 6, 1918. No: 3023 MINING LAW AND ECONOMICS.—1. By DAVID BOWEN, Capt. R.E., With the exception of specialised works of reference intended for legal practitioners and political econo- mists, the. author knows of no book containing a general and elementary account of mining law and economics, and for this reason he has endeavoured in this and following articles to sketch the legal and economic development of mining from the historical point of view, and to prepare the interested reader for some of the administrative difficulties incident to the mining profession. The importance of comparing English law with foreign laws, and thus enabling the conditions under which mining enterprises may be carried on abroad to be appreciated, has not been fully recognised by our mining schools and universities. The curriculum generally includes—as far as mining law is concerned —only the statutory enactments of this country as to the working and management of mines and the pro- visions as to safety of workmen. The student on completing his course of training is thus, as a rule, ignorant of mining law in general. It may be con- tended that legal questions had better be left to legal advisers; but the author is decidedly of opinion that even an elementary knowledge of mining law and economics gives the student and engineer a greater interest in his work, and develops in him a broader intelligence in the administration of his duties. It will be generally admitted, in any case, that this knowledge is of incalculable value in the higher branches of the profession. However, at the present juncture it appears to the author inadvisable to discuss foreign laws as com- pared with English law, except in a brief and very tentative way. Constitutions are in the melting pot as the result of the present war, and it is impossible to foretell what may crystallise in the immediate future. It would be unwise to prophesy, and yet it is difficult to imagine that in countries like Germany and Austria, where constitutional systems aye so thoroughly ingrained in the minds of their people, any radical change in mining codes will be made. As regards this country, it is probable that the economic development of our mining resources will have derived a great impetus from the present war. This is foreshadowed by the recommendations of the Department of Mineral Resources in the United Kingdom, containing in a report to the Minister of Munitions, issued as a White Paper (Cd. 9184 of November 15, 1918). These recommendations are briefly summarised as follows: — 1. That the Government should concern itself more actively than hitherto in the mining and mineral industry at home and in the Crown Colonies and Dependencies. 2. That for this purpose a Mines Department should be organised on suitable lines for the United Kingdom. 3. That at least three advising bodies and com- mittees should be associated with this Department, viz. : — (a) The Imperial Mineral Resources Bureau, in liaison with the self-governing Dominions. (b) The Mines and Minerals Commission to watch over and develop the Empire’s output and trade in mineral and metallic products; (c) Commissioners authorised to take action in cases of improper exploitation of mineral properties or unreasonable or prohibitive conditions imposed by land owners for royal- ties and wayleaves. 4. That a fund, to be administered by the Mines Department and rendered as far as possible self- supporting, should be provided for the purpose of undertaking experimental work in approved direc- tions. 5. That profits spent upon the further development of the properties from which they were derived should be exempted from taxation. 6. That the provisions of the Metalliferous Mines Regulation Act of 1872 should be amended and ex- tended, where necessary, in order to give effect to these recommendations. As there is a great body of opinion in favour of the establishment of such a Department of Mines, it is highly probable that the above recommendations will F.G.S., M.Inst.M.E., etc. substantially — possibly in a modified form — be adopted. Legislative enactments recently passed or at present in contemplation are concerned with— (a) The economic development of mineral re- sources ; (b) The conditions of labour; and (c) The education of the working classes. Each of these questions will be dealt with in the course of tj^is series of articles. HISTORY OF MINING. The history of mining in this country is remarkably interesting as illustrating the development of an industry, the intelligence and ingenuity of people in different stages of civilisation, the growth of the com- mercial spirit, the influence of economic conditions, and the advantage of geographical position. To deal adequately with each of these historical aspects would be impossible within the limits of this lecture, and it is proposed, therefore, to give only a brief account of mining down to within recent times. There are numerous indications that England’s mineral wealth was developed to a certain extent in very early times. The exploitation of tin in Devon and Cornwall is generally referred back to the time of the Phoenician merchants, whilst the Roman work- ings of lead and iron (but particularly lead) have been clearly traced in several districts (Derbyshire, Shropshire, etc.), as has that of salt in Cheshire. Early in the 13th century considerable quantities of tin were exported from Europe. At a still later period tin and lead were regarded as the English minerals of highest commercial value; whereas just before the outbreak of the present war both these minerals, but particularly lead, were comparatively little worked. The iron industry first developed in the neighbour- hood of large supplies of timber, which supplied the smelting medium, charcoal; so that before the use of coal for smelting became general in the latter part of the 18th century, the principal iron districts were centred in the Weald of Kent and Sussex, the Forest of Dean in Gloucestershire, and the neighbourhood of Birmingham. Subsequently the industry followed the development of the coal fields. Crown Rights. Until the year 1688 all mines in England yielding gold and silver belonged to the Crown, and charters were frequently granted in the 14th and 15th cen- turies to adventurers to enter upon private lands to search for minerals. These included lead, tin and copper, each of which contained gold or silver in small quantities. The Court of Exchequer in 1568 affirmed the principle that “ be the quantity of it (gold or silver) ever so small, yet the King shall have the whole of the base metal” containing such small quantities of gold or silver. The rights of the proprietors of the soil were respected to the extent that the charters contained clauses forbidding mining under houses and castles, sometimes also under arable lands and meadows, without their licence. A double royalty was imposed—one to be paid to the King, a second, less in amount, to the landlord. A lease of copper mines by Edward IV. reserves a royalty of one-eighth to the King and one-twelfth to the land- lord ; a lease of lead mines by the same King reserves one-sixteenth to the landlord and one-twelfth to the King. In 1568 an attempt was made to confine the rights of the Crown to mines worked for the precious metals, and to exclude them from those mines in which the precious metals occurred as by-products. But in the case of The Queen v. Northumberland the ancient principle was reaffirmed, three justices dissenting. The decision was, in effect, that only mines containing gold and silver belonged to the Crown, and that the baser metals belonged to the proprietor of the land. This decision carried with it the right of the Crown to enter upon lands to search for gold and silver and to carry on operations necessary for exploiting these minerals. It was also held that a mine worked for baser metals, if it contained gold or silver, belonged to the Crown. The uncertainty to which this, gave rise interfered seriously with the mining indus- try, and led to the passing of the Act of 1 Will. & Mary, c. 30, which enacted that “ noe mine of copper, tin, iron or lead shall hereafter be adjudged reputed or taken to be a Royall Mine although gold or silver may be extracted out of the same.” By this clause an immense property in minerals was trans- ferred immediately to the landlords. By an Act of 1693 (5 Will. & Mary, c. 6) a modification was intro- duced in favour of the Crown. While the subject may under this Act work his base metals at will, the Crown reserves the right of pre-emption of the ore at such prices as would represent its fair value in the absence of royal metals. These prices are fixed by the Act, which, having now become obsolete, the Crown’s rights are never, in fact, exercised, although they were again confirmed by the Act 55 George III., c. 134. But, it should be noted, the Royal preroga- tive in the case of a mine worked for gold or silver, was affirmed by the Court of Appeal in the now famous case of Attorney-General v. Morgan, in 1891. The scarcity of the precious metals in this country towards the close of the Middle Ages led to constant efforts by the Kings themselves to discover these minerals. As the science of mining was at that time very imperfectly understood in this country, whereas it was fully developed on the Continent, foreigners were frequently brought from abroad, as appears from the mining patents granted by Edward IV. and Henry VIII. Under Edward VI. endeavours were made to discover and work mines in Ireland, but without success. The art of smelting and refining was so little understood that, under Mary, a Commission was appointed to learn metallurgy from a German adventurer. Mining engineers were, in the time of Elizabeth, still largely German. The rights of the Crown naturally cheeked mining enterprise until the Act of 1693, .from which it received a great impetus. Alum Mines. Alum mines were occasionally claimed by the Crown as affording the basis for the manufacture of gun- powder, and in the reign of James. I. all the judges held that the Crown could grant licences for working saltpetre for gunpowder in any lands of the subject for the defence of the realm, though the owners of the land were also left at liberty to mine upon their own account. Coal Mining. The chief mineral industry of the country at the present day—coal mining—was practised in the North of England and South of Scotland in very early times. Doubtless this was the case also in all the other coal fields, but originally working was confined to the outcrops simply or for only short distances from the surface. In a charter of 1234 there is an indication of the Northumberland coal supply, while the York- shire coal field is first mentioned early in the follow- ing century. The leasehold system with royalties appears to have been common in the 14th century. On account of the fear felt that the supply of coal might rapidly be exhausted if intensive exploitation were permitted, it was a frequent practice of the lords - of the soil to expressly limit the quantity of coal which might be worked per day. It was the prevalent opinion that coal could only be worked near the sur- face. In 1610 Sir George Selby informed Parliament that the coal supply of Newcastle would be exhausted in 21 years. This*fear of exhaustion stimulated in- vention for draining and ventilating mines, and from this it may be said that the whole art of modern mining sprang. But it is interesting to note that, whereas in 1700 it was estimated that the total pro- duction amounted to only 2,612,000 tons, and in 1800 to 10,080,000 tons, the returned total (for the United Kingdom) in 1913 amounted to 287,411,869 tons, of the total value of £145,535,669. Modern Legislation. Until the 19th century, except in the case of Royal mines, there existed no statutory regulations for the working, management, and inspection of mines, nor for the security for those employed. Previous enact- ments were concerned only with the regulation of possession of property in mines or with the special remedies open to mine owners against acts of wrong- doing on the part of employees. The year 1842, in which the Mines Regulation Act, 5 & 6 Viet., c. 99, was passed, marks the beginning of mining legislation in the modern sense. By this Act it was forbidden to employ females underground after March 1, 1843. The employment of boys under 10 was also forbidden. The inspection of coal mines by Government was under- taken in 1850 under the terms of the Act 13 & 14 Viet., e. 100, which authorised the appointment of inspectors. Similar provisions were enacted in 1872 (35 & 36 Viet., c. 77) in connection with metalliferous mines. This Act raised the age of boys to 12, following the precedent set in the Mines Regulation Act of 1860 (23 & 24 Viet., c. 151). Mining legislation in the case of both classes of mines—coal mines and metal mines—has developed along parallel lines, that of coal mines being specially distinguished in character by special provisions dealing with the precautions to be observed with a view to the prevention of the peculiar classes of accidents incidental to coal mining, explo- sions, etc. Provisions common to both are those pro- hibiting the paying of wages in public-houses , those under which notification must be made to inspectors of accidents explosions, etc. ; rules as to the opening and working of new shafts ; and codes of offences in the nature of contravention of the rules for the safe working of mines approved by the Secretary of State. The principal Acts now in force will be discussed in a subsequent lecture. It should be noted that the statutory regulation of mines is within the jurisdiction of the Secretary of State for Home Affairs.