March 14, 1913. THE COLLIERY GUARDIAN. 539 logic, the question was not one that only touched the Government claims for duty; that was a minor matter compared with the buying and selling of mineral estates, as whichever principle was right referred to both. Mr. Stephen had put before them a tangible proposition, in the case he had taken, and to arrive at the valuation desired there were certain points to be considered. As they were dealing with a mineral area the commercial success was not the main element, as the physical difficulties which might rain one concern might be conquered by another, and that would be covered by the rate of interest taken. The 10 per cent, under all the circumstances seemed reasonable, but to deal with it on the Inwood tables, assuming a one rate compounded for the whole period, surely could not be right. It struck him that Mr. Stephen went wrong in assuming a recurring risk instead of a continuing one. The climax or loss could only take place once, and the risk was not cumulative. Finally the speakers, upon the proposition they were considering, was convinced the owner of proved minerals, with the prospect of receiving £3,750 per annum for 84 years, although deferred 36 years, would not accept anything like so small a sum as £1,211, and further the colliery owners with a prospect of a further life of 84 years, with a saving in royalty of £3,750 per annum for the period, would probably give more than the £12,101, especially if there was an open market and competition. * Mr. J. C. McLaren (Birmingham University) said that he was only able to give the facts as they appeared to him as a mathematician, the technical points being outside his range. He had read Mr. O’Donahue’s paper and Mr. Stephen’s pamphlet, and it appeared to him that the latter’s arguments were entirely sound and his methods logical and properly worked out. A 10 per cent, basis might not be a fair one at all, but once they necessary indication of approximate value, they were to a very great extent only a means to an end. The broad view that he took was that no person would pay anything approaching the sum suggested looking at the thing as a person would have to look at it calculated upon the table. No person would think of paying down £12,000 with the prospect of getting at the end of the period only three times that amount, seeing that the prospect was subject to all the factors represented by possible legislation, changes in the relations between capital and labour and in taxation and all the other things which might have to be taken into account. Therefore it seemed to him perfectly clear that the risk and the discounting which, independently of the tables, had to be taken into consideration, formed a factor which must be taken as extending throughout the whole of the deferred period as well as through the active time of the realisation of the annuity. Mr. S. L. Thacker thought the question of the probability of the coal and all considerations affecting the prospective yield and value of the property should be settled before the mathematical calculation was commenced. When one considered an investment to be deferred 36 years and considered market values, he did not think 10 per cent, would be a sufficient return. That was the whole point as to the general value of property, but that did not affect the mathematics of the problem at all. The whole question was, “ What do you mean when you say you must have a certain term, and you must have that at simple interest or compound interest ? ” Mr. O’Donahue was then called upon to reply. He said he was pleased to have an opportunity of replying to Mr. Daniel Stephen’s criticism of his paper, but he regretted that the criticism was first published in a manner by which he was precluded from replying The result was follows:— where + A = present value of an annuity of 1 for n years deferred d years. Alw -f- d = amount of an annuity of 1 for n + d years at rate s. Rlw + d = amount of £1 for n + d years at rate s. Aw = amount of an annuity of 1 for n years at rate Vr. Aw + d = amount of an annuity of 1 for n + d years at rate Vr. r = accumulative rate of interest. s = speculative rate of interest. He might be allowed to explain that the difference between the rule which he had previously given and the one above was the same as that between the dual rate of interest method and the single rate of interest method as applied to an immediate annuity. The former allows the higher rate of interest on the original capital for the whole period, whereas the latter allows the higher rate of interest on outstanding capital only. As he previously explained, either method might be applied; the second method showed the true rate of interest allowed, and with the former method the effective rate of interest was somewhat higher than the nominal rate. Mr. Stephen’s logical premises were quite sound—his application of them was quite the opposite. He failed to appreciate the fact that the year was merely a period arbitrarily fixed for converting interest, and that it could not be assumed that such a period represented an operation in an investment analogous to the tossing of a coin. His own method of dealing with deferred annuities was to allow the same rate of interest whether the annuity was deferred or immediate. To argue that the value of such a property was £ e. 2600 23'00 2*00 £300 22.00 £>O0 E000 I0OO 14-00 'SOO 1200 Il Oo lOOo 900 8oo IfcOO I JOO 1600 \5oa £ "Zjoo ZiOO ; 2 5.00 24-0 0 ,2500 .22.00 .2100 2000 U90O • i9oo 1700 .1600 1500 •1300 1200 -UQXL IOOO 900 800 JOO bQO 500 ^00 3oo Zoo I 100 JOO 600 532 *4 SQ9 466 70 /♦oo Joo •Zoo J J 3 U £ Z]0» ifeoo" 2600 2400 >3 2200 2/00 2000 tQoo /Soo 1700 *600 1600 >4-00 1300 1100 2700 ZbOO 2500 2*00 23oo 2200 2iOO 2000 i^OO »Soo 1700 16OO '5‘UP IttCO 1300 <000 •)00 Soo 706 690 500 300 20 e 100 • 1 oo 1000 qao aoo 7°° > J 5324$Soo 3 4-on 41. 31^'15 300 I s Zoo. too Fig. 2.—Diagram No. 1. started with it they must not introduce a small rate of /interest in order to calculate for the redemption of capital. The reason was obvious. All returns from the colliery, whether they called them redemption of capital or profit, were loaded with the same risk. The 10 per cent, allowance was not really accumulative interest at all; it was simply a method. Mr. W. Bentley (Birmingham) said as far as his little experience in that district went they had always worked on Inwood’s tables. When they were buying an annuity they expected to get back their capital during the time the annuity was running, together with interest at the agreed rate on the amount of capital from time to time at risk. If that was the right view of it, all questions of double rates of interest, remunera- tive rate and accumulative rate went by the board, because as soon as the money went into their pockets it was out of risk altogether. What they had to get back again was their principal, not at the end of the trans- action, but from time to time by instalments as the annuity ran on. Several persons to whom he had spoken on the subject of valuations seemed to him to be paying rather too much attention to the question of Estate Duty. He knew that that was the old valuer’s idea for probate ; but there was the question of incre- ment duty, and he hoped they would carefully consider the effect of increment duty on very small areas which would work out in a few years after the coal had been •entered upon. Mr. Arthur Sopwith said that they had heard a great deal of the question of the mathematical working out of valuations, but the conclusion he had come to was that while the tables, whether Hoskold’s or Inwood’s -or any others, were a very good, valuable and absolutely immediately. The rules he suggested would mean higher values for Estate Duty. He wondered if the writer of the review would have so readily condemned his methods had he realised that increased increment value duties would fall to be paid on unworked minerals if the old rules were adopted. The capital values were now being settled, and his difficulty—despite his rules— was to make valuations high enough to satisfy owners, as the majority of them were prepared to risk the relatively lower rate of duty payable for probate rather than the higher increment value duty. Mr. Stephen purported to deal with three of his methods. He could not have given his 1906 paper very careful attention, or he would have known that he gave no such rule in 1906 as the one he quoted. He gave that particular rule in his last paper, with the qualification that it could not logically be applied in the manner in which he had applied it. Mr. Stephen next stated that in 1912 he extended the Birmingham 1906 method to obtain the practical rule which he (Mr. O’Donahue) advocated. He did nothing of the kind. It should be quite clear to anyone who had read both papers that the rule which he gave in 1906 for deferred annuities was identical with the one advocated in his last paper. It was a difficult matter to meet a criticism which contained so many misstatements on points of fact, and most of the ninepins which Mr. Stephen knocked down were of his own manu- facture. With regard to the “theoretical” rule, he (Mr« O’Donahue) had something to add to what he stated in the last paper. He had not then succeeded in deducing for that method a formula which was simple enough for ordinary application. By approaching the problem in another way he had latterly been more successful. Fig. 3.—Diagram No. 2. £1,211, was equivalent to saying that it was probable that on the average 30 properties of similar risk would be required to realise the revenue estimated to be derived from the one. Mr. Stephen, sen., appeared to have a suspicion that the £1,211 was too low, and no practical man would hesitate in coming to that conclusion. It should be noted that deferment of realisation had no effect theoretically so long as interest was accu- mulating. The ordinary individual was naturally desirous of realising within his lifetime, and con- sequently competition for the purchase of long- deferred payments was restricted, but to the State or to corporate bodies deferment mattered nothing, and they would make a very fine investment if they could purchase all unworked minerals on the 10 per cent, compound interest basis. He had been asked if he could not present the problem in such a manner as to clear it from the cloud of complicated mathematical calculations, and it had occurred to him that the accompanying charts might possibly serve the purpose. The horizontal lines of the charts represented years, a period of 30 years, and the vertical lines represented pounds. The curve A Z showed the accumulation of an annuity of £100 a year for 20 years at 3 per cent. The curve B Z showed the accumulation of an annuity of £56 48 per annum for 30 years at 3 per cent. The curve C Z showed that a present sum of £1,107, invested at 3 per cent., accumu- lated to £2,687 in 30 years, just as each of the two annuities amounted to the same value in 30 years. Assume that the two annuities, instead of being secured properties, were estimated to be derived from mineral estates. The “ full ” value at the end of the 30 years