538 THE COLLIERY GUARDIAN. March 14, 1913. 84 years. On behalf of the owner, he met the mineral valuer stationed at Bradford. They agreed upon all the factors affecting the valuation—that is, the deferred period, the active period of the royalty, the area of the field, thickness and price per foot per acre, and the rate of discount—but on calculating the present value from all the known factors they found there was a wide difference between them, the district valuer’s amount being 10 times his own amount. As none of the data were in dispute, the difference was one solely of calcula- tion—in fact, a difference of interpretation as to the meaning of one of the functions—and on further correspondence it was found that they did not attach the same meaning to the expression “ discounted at the rate of 10 per cent, per annum.” The writer thereupon asked his son and partner, Mr. Daniel Stephen, to ascertain as far as possible all the meanings which had been attached to the expression, and to find out any fallacies in them. He had put the result in the form of a pamphlet (see p. 542 of this issue) as a contribution to the subject of that afternoon’s discussion. Mr. Stephen observed that the expected rents from a mine could be quite correctly considered as a deferred annuity, and the value calculated by finding a capital sum to accumulate during the deferred period, and then to provide the annuity and a sinking fund during the active period. If this was done there were three rates of interest to be determined:—(1) The rate for the deferred period, (2) the rate for the active period, (3) the rate for the sinking fund. The method of dealing with tie problem was extremely complex, gave rise to much difference of opinion with respect to the various rates of interest to be charged, but when calculated, after taking into account all the conditions, gave the same result as obtained in the method advocated. The modern practice by public authorities of borrowing money, and providing a sinking fund for repayment, had probably suggestedthe method of dealing with the present values of mining royalties in the same way. The problems in the two cases were best solved by different methods, and it was much simpler in the theory of the calculation of the present values of mining royalties, instead of using the annuity and sinking fund method, to use the discount method, and deal with each expected year’s rent by itself as a capital sum, and find its present value, as was done in last chapter of the pamphlet. If this method was followed only one question arose, and that was: “At what rate shall a capital sum be discounted for a given number of years?” When this rate had been decided, each year’s expected rent could be discounted by itself as a capital sum for the determined number of years, and the total present value obtained by adding each of the present values together. When it was admitted that the method of calculation put forward in the pamphlet was correct in principle, there might be a further objection raised that, with the rate of interest so high as 10 per cent., the result of the calculation did not correspond with the amounts, known to be paid as the result of experience in the open market. This objection was foreign to the pamphlet itself, which was concerned solely with the method of calculation, and applied just as truly whether the rate was taken at 10 per cent, or 8 per cent, or any smaller percentage. The rate of interest had first to be determined as a rate for discounting capital sums, and this could be done oply from general considerations quite independent of and prior to the determination of how the calculation should be made. It was submitted, however, that the calculated result substantially agreed with experience. Estates were put up to auction which were expected to have coal underneath them, but where neither the depth, thickness, nor quality of the seams were known. The intervening strata might be water- bearing, and there was no expectation of working being commenced within 30 years. In such cases it was a general experience that very little if any more money was paid than if the coal was not expected to be there. If, however, in any case there was a discrepancy, it was properly overcome by reconsidering the rate of interest and not by the substitution of an erroneous method of calculation. The Finance Act, 1909-10, by itself had raised the question of the present values of deferred mining rents to a position of much more importance than it was previous to the passing of the Act, on account of the more detailed and local machinery provided by the Act for ascertaining the present values. This was, however, of small importance in comparison with the change proposed to be made by the valuers themselves in the method of calculation. Mr. W. M. Miller (Edinburgh) wrote that he did not think Mr. O’Donahue, in his reply to his (Mr. Miller’s) former remarks had appreciated the points he was desirous of making. For instance, fears as to future legislation could scarcely be met by a deduction from estimated revenue. Again, if Mr. O’Donahue wished the formula referred to by him to be adopted for general application, he (Mr. Miller) thought it was incumbent on him to explain how it could be satisfactory when it produced paradoxical results, in very ordinary instances, such as had been set forth in the discussion. Mr. O’Donahue referred to “ Mr. Miller’s intuitive method of valuing without rules or tables.” It must surely have been apparent from his (Mr. Miller’s) remarks that he was in the habit of using Hoskold’s tables, and of course selecting the rate of interest accordingly. The discussion tended to confirm him in his view that attention was rather being directed to what a person ought to give for a property than to what he would give. It was of no use telling a purchaser of minerals that he was only entitled to interest on his out- standing capital, and not on his original outlay, and that he must apportion part of the annual return for redemption purposes and invest it at a particular rate, which he might very probably not be able to obtain. He wanted something more practical than that, and particularly where there was no immediate revenue in prospect he was very chary about purchasing. One had only to look at the amount of mineral property in the market seeking purchasers, and not even attracting an offer, to realise that an extraordinarily high rate of interest must be allowed, if Mr. O’Donahue’s formulae be used, to arrive at valuations which there was any like- lihood of a purchaser considering reasonable. Differing from Mr. Smith, he (Mr. Miller) was of opinion that there is an additional increment of risk due to deferment such as to warrant the substitution of compound interest at the high rate in calculating the accumulation of capital during the deferred period. He could see little use in extreme refinement of calculation when the lowest valuation might be upset within a year by the imposition of a Mineral Rights Duty of Is. per £, or when a valua- tion might be rendered useless by a minimum wage or similar Act being passed, converting it from a profitable to an unprofitable concern; or even as regards a very profitable colliery when a profit tax such as that announced in France a few days ago might be imposed at any time appropriating to the Government up to one-third of the profits earned. In his opinion Hoskold’s deferred tables did not make more than sufficient allow- ance for such contingencies. If it were agreed in a particular case with a life of, say, 30 years, that 10 per cent, was a reasonable rate of interest, his (Mr. Miller’s) contention was that if the first five or ten years were cut out and only the remainder were for sale, then it required the valuation to be not higher than that given by Hoskold to find a purchaser. If the valuation was made on Mr. O’Donahue’s system, then a higher rate of interest must be used for the deferred period than was considered suitable for the full period, otherwise a purchaser would not be got. Something more than formulae and tables were required for valuing mineral property. Dr. R. S. Heath (Birmingham University), in a written communication, said the only question at issue was whether 10 per cent, was a fair percentage to anticipate during what he might call the “ period of incubation” of the property as well as the period of actual working. Discussing the problem enunciated by Mr. Stephen, he said the purchaser presumably had many securities to choose from, some free from risk, producing say a safe 3 per cent, as well as that some- what risky mining investment. All through the period of incubation the purchase money was locked up in mining securities ; the purchaser must therefore estimate the profit at 10 per cent. The whole return was speculative—each instalment of £3,750 which was to accrue later was tinged with that speculative character, and might through the risks of mining enterprise turn out to be far less than the estimate. The purchaser would not be justified in making the purchase unless he could estimate the return at the rate of 10 per cent, from the first and all through the period of incubation. It was indeed all through the period of incubation just as much as during the subsequent working of the property, that the owner was exposed to special risks. It was, therefore, his opinion that each deferred pay- ment of rent should be discounted at the full 10 per cent. He had arrived at tke same conclusion as Mr. Stephen through his argument of probabilities. Mr. R. F. Percy (Nottingham) also wrote to say that the truth appeared to be that whatever the particular method preferred by the valuer, if he appreciated the mathematics of the formula and its proper application to the particular case, he would arrive at a fair value. There could be no absolute or exact value, for indefinite properties must have indefinite values. Two valuers attacking the same problem would probably arrive near the same point although proceeding by different routes —that was, provided they both endeavoured to reach a just solution ; but if they approached the problem with no intention of arriving at an equitable mean, one seeking to find a high value and the other a low one, the capital values they deduced would inevitably exhibit marked disparity. He fully subscribed to Mr. O’Donahue’s remark that the “ two-rate-throughout ” method, “ although open to criticism of principle, is the only satisfactory method for general application.” It should be borne in mind that the argument which defeated Hoskold’s method of deferment is equally fatal to Inwood’s. To arrive at present values by the 1906 method, the writer some years ago constructed a slide rule, which proved to be a very handy instrument, but he afterwards replaced this by tables similar to that given by Mr. O’Donahue later. These tables were computed for seven rates, and are nearly complete for 100 years, but they were only correct to three figures. In conclusion, Mr. Percy said he ventured to give the following rules:— Hoskold’s Values.—Take the amount of £1 per annum at the low rate for the term, and multiply it by the figure in the table for the same period. Example.—The value of £1 per annum for 20 years at 8 per cent, for remuneration and 3 per cent, for redemp- tion is 26’870 x -3175 = £8-531. Deferred Annuity Two-rates-throughout.—Take the amount of £1 per annum at the low rate for the period of enjoyment and multiply by the figure in the table for the total period (deferment plus enjoyment). The example given would be thus simplified:— 11464 x *3497 x 1,000 = £4,008. It was very desirable for mining engineers to adopt a uniform method if possible; and if Mr. O’Donahue could make his theo- retical method workable by designing a formula by which the high rate of remuneration should alone be deemed to be yielded by the capital value, and which at the same time provided that with the repayment of the capital the high rate dividends should correspondingly decrease, the writer would be ready to bring it into practical use without delay, and do his best to persuade other mining engineers to adopt it also. Mr. W. A. Mason (Birmingham) wrote to suggest that the two contentions might be stated thus:— 1. Is the investment to be considered “ wild cat ” for 120 years ? 2. Or is it to be considered “ gilt edge ” for 36 years and “ wild cat ” for 84 years ? Personally, he could not see any reasons to suggest that the risks of the first period were less than those of the second. Mr. G. M. Cockin thought they were all agreed that a high rate of interest was expected—at least 10 per cent. But a great difference of opinion prevailed as to the interest to be allowed for redemption of capital, and these differences in the interest to be allowed gave widely differing results. People talked about high and low valuations ; but what was required was a true valuation. Mr. Alexander Smith (Birmingham) said that on a previous occasion he had given his views; and although he could not agree with Mr. Donahue through all his methods, he supported his view as to the treatment of annuities during a period of deferment. He held that the essence of all investment was that the original capital outlay should be kept intact, and the transaction should arrange for the annuity giving the interest earned, and such an amount for redemption fund as could be invested immediately without trouble, which would be something gilt-edged, and accumulate to the outlay at the end of the term. He therefore could not agree with one rate of interest, as it was not convenient to deal with sums at high rates; neither was it in keeping with the safe return of the capital, as the high rates gave much increased risk. Neither did he agree with Mr. O’Donahue’s ingenious methods of showing that as the investor was getting his capital reduced by each payment of the redemption fund, he should be allowed interest on the outstanding capital only, as the calculation was for an interest to reproduce the capital sum during the period of the annuity. That, however, was a minor matter, and the tug of war came in dealing with the deferred annuities. If one were a buyer, he would like to adopt Mr. Stephen’s method, and if selling that of Mr. O’Donahue; but one must be consistent, and he would like to remove an impression that the Government valuers were out for plunder, as this could not be, for what they gained in death duties they would lose in increment. As he stated in the last discussion, he agreed with Mr. O’Donahue, that it was only fair to take the two rates of interest during the time of defer- ment, as the whole risk was covered by the high rate adopted, and there was no such additional increment of risks due to the deference of payment as to warrant the substitution of compound interest at the high rate in calculating the accumulation of capital during the deferred period. When they came to the tables and the