October 25, 1918. THE COLLIERY GUARDIAN. 867 scarce for forward booking. Little if any house coal is offered in the open market in Manchester, and the supply in Yorkshire is inadequate. Slacks are scarce. No surplus of superior grades is available in Cardiff for private trade. Secondary sorts and best bunker smalls are going well, but inferior grades are accumulating. Supplies do not equal the continued active demand in Scotland. Patent fuel makers in South Wales are busy, and could greatly increase the output if labour were obtainable. Chartering remains dull, and the tone for Scandi- navian ports has been rather variable in Newcastle. Rates are firmly maintained in Cardiff. The Coal Controller’s figures for the four weeks ended September 14 show an increase of 1,800,000 on the previous four weeks, but a decrease of 1,758,000 compared with the corresponding period last year. A Government report at an early date will embody the results of investigations carried out by the Director of Fuel Research into the use of pulverised coal for metallurgical and other purposes in the United States. The Board of Trade has issued an Order requiring weekly returns from all persons consuming two or more tons of coal or coke per week. The Petroleum Production Bill and the Petroleum Production (No. 2) Bill were both read a second time in the House of Lords on Tuesday, and the motion to refer both to a Select Committee was negatived without a division. The Miners’ Federation of South Wales decided to call a coal-field conference failing a satisfactory reply to the demand for an eight hours day for surface workmen. The annual meeting of the North Staffordshire Institute of Mining Engineers will be held in the Central School of Science and Technology, Stoke- on-Trent, on November 4, commencing at 5 p.m. A special commission to inquire into conditions and Government reductions affecting the coal industry in foreign countries will shortly leave the United States for Europe. The question of coal and mineral Coal traffic on the railways of the United Transport. Kingdom has recently been discussed in considerable detail by Mr. Kelw’ay-Bamber, in a paper read before the Institution of Locomotive Engineers, and, as the full text has now been published in the journal of that institution, we take the opportunity of discussing its main features. The chief object of the paper was to indicate a method whereby the load-carrying capacity of British railways, and their revenue-earning powers, might, in the author’s opinion, be sub- stantially increased. As the net result claimed for this scheme amounts to a considerable reduction in dead weight hauled, in addition to other economies, Mr. Bamber’s plan certainly merits serious attention, even although it is not put forward as a scheme which could be at once put into operation, but rather as a possible achievement in the course of the next decade. Briefly, the suggestion is based upon the proved efficiency, under certain conditions, of the high- capacity wagon, of a type similar to those already in use in South Africa. The subject is not by any means new, but it has not before been handled in such thorough detail. There is no doubt, also, that the tendency in some countries has been progressively in favour of increased carrying capacity of coal wagons. In India, for example, there has been a gradual rise in the load of four-wheeled mineral wagons, which has now reached 23*25 tons, the body length remaining constant at 19*25 ft. This is rendered possible by the fact that the Indian railways concerned have a broad gauge, 5 ft. 6 in. A similar tendency is also seen in the mineral railways of the United States, whose gauge is 4 ft. 8J in. The 3 ft. 6 in. gauge of South African railways, however, closely corresponds with that of the railways of Great Britain, and that country, therefore, serves well for the purpose of comparing the relative efficiency of high and low capacity wagons. Mr. Bamber very properly urges the importance of increasing the coal-carrying and revenue-earning capacity of British railways as a pure measure of reconstruction after the war. It is a question which was referred to by Sir Albert Stanley, in his lecture at Saddler’s Hall, to which we drew attention in this column a week ago. It is not, of course, to be expected that any proj ect for increasing the gauge of- English railways would be regarded as a practical proposition at the present time. But Mr. Bamber confines his attention to what might be done to increase the efficiency and reduce the working costs in this country within the existing limitations of British main line load restrictions. He claims that the South African railways are using the most up-to-date coal wagons extant complying in over-all height and width with the requirements of the railways of Great Britain, and running under very severe conditions both of grade and curve. These are the 45-ton bogie, flat bottom high-sided, and 45-ton bogie self-discharging hopper coal wagons. It can easily be shown statistically that these high capacity wagons possess considerable advantages, which may be summarised as follows :—The number of vehicles to be handled is reduced by 77 per cent. ; there is an improvement in the percentage of paying load to gross weight hauled by 22 per cent.; the dead weight hauled is reduced by 33| per cent.; the coal consumption is diminished by about 40 per cent. ; the train length is reduced by about 47 per cent.; and the gross weight per foot of wagon length is increased by about 63 per cent. In addition to these improvements may be added the increased efficiency of both locomotives and sidings. But there are obvious obj ections to the application of Mr. Bamber’s plan to the railways of this country. In the first place, it is necessary to remember that the English railways are at a disadvantage in com- parison with those of newer countries. Our railways were made under conditions which hardly exist in the case of South Africa or the United States, where the railroads act as pioneers in opening up new towns, and are comparatively free from such obstruc- tions to the loading gauge as tunnels and overhead bridges. There are, also, in Great Britain no such long-distance haulages as exist in the above-named countries. Then it is also necessary to consider the conditions of trade, and the proportion of small traders. There are large numbers of coal merchants in Great Britain who would be unable to handle large consignments. Colliery screening and delivery appliances, and the wagon tips at docks are not in general adapted for dealing with coal wagons of 45- ton capacity. As was pointed out by Mr. A. D. Jones, the president of the Institution of Locomotive Engineers, in discussing Mr. Bamber’s paper, the transport point of view is not the only one to be considered. It is not contended that existing arrange- ments in this country are the best from an economic standpoint, but these conditions exist, and have grown up with the coal trade. To alter them in order to make larger units general would be a matter of considerable difficulty. High capacity wagons, up to 30 tons, have, it is true, come into use for special purposes, and perhaps there may be discerned a growing tendency to increase the capacity of ordinary coal wagons, which are now commonly constructed to carry 15 or 20 tons ; but it would seem beyond the bounds of feasibility to expect a whole- sale conversion to 45-ton capacities within anything like the limit of time suggested by Mr. Bamber, except by the aid of the most drastic legislation, involving the compulsory scrapping of much existing plant. The war has taught us, among many other things, however, that there is undoubtedly room for consider- able improvement in the handling of the coal traffic on British railways. Sir Albert Stanley has hinted that a complete reversion to pre-war methods is not to be expected. Mr. Bamber, therefore, has done good service in dealing with this question from the traffic standpoint, and his figures appear to be quite incontrovertible. We should like, however, to see the question treated also from the point of view of capital expenditure involved in making so great a revolution in practice as this scheme would entail. Not that this would necessarily prove prohibitive in view of the large annual saving that might be effected. But the financial question is, nevertheless, an important consideration, and one that must necessarily prove a vital factor in any proposition of this nature. A paper by Dr. J. 0. Stamp, Trade published recently in the Journal Fluctuations of the Royal Statistical Society, and Profits, examines the effect of trade fluctua- tions upon profits, as revealed by statistics. The subject is interesting in itself; but Dr. Stamp’s treatment of is particularly so, owing to the large part that is taken up by a discus- sion of coal-mining profits. This attempt to estab- lish a correlation between trade movements and trade profits is new. As the author says, “ with all the recent mass of writing on trade cycles and the skilful production of ‘business barometers,’ there is little to show us from the most accurately adjusted barometer and skilled reading of its movements what precisely is the change ‘ in the weather ’ that may be expected to follow or accompany its indica- tions.” The reason for this, in his opinion, lies in the difficulty of obtaining sufficiently accurate informa- tion to enable a proper comparison to be made between profits and trade statistics. This is very true. Few people have ever considered statistics from this point of view. There is no very precise knowledge respecting the relative influence of quan- tity and price upon profits, and most business men are particularly shy of statistics when applied to the practical purpose of predicting the future trend of trade. Dr. Stamp has already done valuable service in his careful analysis of the profits represented by the assessments to income tax under Schedule D, pub- lished in the volume, “ British Incomes and Property: The Application of Official Statistics to Economic Problems.” * The present paper is, in fact, an application of the results arrived at in that volume to the practical problem of establishing a rel.tionship between trade activity and profit making. His * London: P. S. King and Son Limited, 1916. object is not to discover a causal relation so much as to examine what evidence there is of concomitant variation. He acknowledges many difficulties in estimating for any trade the connection between output and profit, and not the least of them is the extreme complexity of such statistics of profits as are available. Taking, for example, coal mining, it happens that income tax assessments on mines have always been shown separately. The fact that metal- liferous mines are included probably makes very little difference, since their number is relatively unimpor- tant. These assessments, also, are based on the average profits of the preceding five years. Dr. Stamp gives a diagram showing, by means of a curve, the fluctuations in coal profits between the years 1871 and 1913, based upon these five-year averages. From these curves he deduces the nine- years moving average and the linear trend for specified periods, whence a coefficient of deviation is obtained, and certain equations are established. We do not, however, propose to follow Dr. Stamp in his purely statistical methods, not only because it would be difficult to do so in the space at our command, but also because such a course would be unprofitable to the non-statistical reader. Fortunately, in the case of coal mining, other statistics are available in addi- tion to income tax returns. A Parliamentary paper (No. 197 of 1903), on “ Wages and Profits in Coal Mining,” gives for the years 1886 to 1902, average prices, computed wages, computed receipts and gross profits for each year. The figures for gross profits are merely the balance after deducting wages from receipts, and since they include royalties and other expenses, they are very different from net profits. Nevertheless, these figures may be legi- timately used for comparative purposes, and when thrown into a series of curves certain relationships can be established. Thus, looking first at the years in which there is a negligible change in output, it is assumed that the whole change in profits is due to change in price. Upon this assumption, it is found that for a change in price represented by one point, profits change three and a third points. It is also deduced that a change of one point in output involves a profit change of rather more than one point, but probably not greater than 1’5. Taking next the years in which there were increases in profits, and using 1*5 as the common factor to eliminate the effect of the output changes, the author finds that in the case of small changes (less than 30 points), the profit change is 2’5 per unit of price change, and in the case of large changes, 2*7 per unit of price change ; or 2’57 for all increases. In the case of decreases in profits, it can similarly be shown that the profit change per unit of price is 3*7 for small changes, 4’1 for large changes, or 3*8 for all decreases. From this the interesting result is obtained that a rise in price has had less effect in raising profits than a fall in prices has had in diminishing them, and the difference is more pronounced in the case of large changes than for small ones. Again, where a year of rising profit is followed by another rise, or conversely where a year of fall is followed by another fall, the succeeding year tends to show a diminished factor, i.e., the effect of the second price change in altering profits is not so great as the first. He attributes this to the rapidity with which wages follow prices in the coal industry. If allowance is made for the fact that royalties do not usually vary with the price of coal, and that the whole of the fluctuation in price is borne by the coal owner, the broad fact emerges that price has been fully four times as powerful as output in causing fluctuations in coal mining profits. It is necessary, however, here to repeat the caution that what are called profits in the Parliamentary return are not net profits, but simply the balance left after subtracting wages from the total receipts. It is interesting also to compare the curve based upon the Parliamentary return with that repre- senting the income tax assessments, the most noticeable feature being the lag in the peak positions shown in the latter, making it appear as if the profits of one year were influenced by the trade activities of the year following. Thus the year 1900 was one of abnormally high prices and high profits. But this is not reflected in the income tax assess- ments until the year 1901. Dr. Stamp finds that the reason for this is to be found in the statutory pro- vision for special relief in income tax assessments when there is a sequence of diminishing profits (known as the 133rd Section). The effect of this is partly to advance profits a year, i.e., the assessments ecorded for 1900 would approximate actually to the profits of 1901. It must be remembered, also, that the income tax assessments are five-year averages only, and do not fully reflect the true condition. Thus, even when the profits are nil, dead rents and royalties would still be assessed, so that the effect of bad times is not fully shown, and the actual fluctua- tions from the highest to the lowest point of aggregate profits is wider than the figures would indicate. Nevertheless, these diagrams, and Dr. Stamp’s deductions from them, are highly instructive to students of the economics of the coal industry. We have confined the above remarks to the coal mining industry only, although Dr. Stamp’s paper